Some of the worst water quality problems result from
nutrient leaching and runoff from agricultural lands. Nitrogen and phosphorus applied to cropland
and not absorbed by crops in the process of photosynthesis will, one way or
another, one day or another, end up in the water. The same goes for animal waste. The nutrients
cause algae blooms, reduced concentrations of dissolved oxygen, and diminished
fisheries and ecosystem health (called eutrophication).
While there has been some effort to deal with these problems,
I know of no great success stories, and water quality continues to decline in
the Mississippi, the Gulf of Mexico, and the Chesapeake, the Great Lakes, and
countless other water bodies.
One obvious remedy would be to tax fertilizer. This would be a nearly Pigouvian
solution. Better would be to tax runoff
and leaching directly, but that’s basically impossible for practical reasons.
The obvious but rarely stated problem is that it would
probably require an extraordinarily large tax to have any real influence on the
quantity of fertilizer used. And
politically powerful farmers would cry foul, which is why this kind of tax will
probably never happen.
But I wonder: What would the incidence of a fertilizer tax,
broadly applied, really be? Agriculture
is fairly competitive. And demand for
agricultural commodities is nearly vertical—about as inelastic as
anything. The econ 101 analysis would
suggest that burden of the tax would fall mainly on consumers. That is, food commodity prices would go up
enough to compensate for most all of the tax.
Now, I’ve seen some economists propose fertilizer taxes on a
graduated scale. If fertilizer is
applied at a sufficiently low rate, no tax would be levied, but the tax would
then rise sharply with higher application levels (which is where most runoff
and leaching comes from). This would be
a little harder to monitor, but probably not too bad. If done this way, the total tax bill would
cost farmers far less, but cause the same reduction in fertilizer use. And farmers would still get the full
compensating price increase, since less output would be collectively produced.
I think it’s possible—indeed, very probable—that the induced
rise in commodity prices would more than compensate farmers for the fertilizer
taxes they would have to pay under the graduated tax system. That is, a statutory tax on farmers could
cause their profits to go up.
Anyway, I don’t think anyone has made this point or emphasized it very well. And it’s an important one, at least politically
speaking, because maybe farmers could get on board with a tax that actually
benefits them. I’m not sure if it would
save the Chesapeake Bay or Great Lakes from eutrophication, but I bet it would
do a lot more good than anything else that’s been tried.
Update: Of course, this is no free lunch: consumers would pay in higher food prices.
Update: Of course, this is no free lunch: consumers would pay in higher food prices.